full article:
Introduction
The poor status of Aboriginal health in Australia in general and in central Australia in particular is well documented1-4. The status of Aboriginal health in central Australia is not unrelated to concern for the environmental status of the central Australian rangelands. To the first non-Aboriginal settlers in central Australia, the then existing vegetative cover gave the erroneous impression of high productivity to which they responded with the introduction of domestic livestock. This resulted in ecological degradation manifested in soil loss, decreased vegetative cover, and loss of native species5,6. Further ecological impacts resulted from the invasion of feral species such as camels, horses, donkeys, foxes, cats and buffel grass (Cenchrus ciliarus) and changed fire regimes. While some Aboriginal people maintained links to country, non-Aboriginal settlement in central Australia has resulted in a changed relationship for many Aboriginal people with their country, and has contributed to a decline in ecosystem services and to poor Aboriginal health. Even with the re-establishment of Aboriginal access to traditional country, the uptake and application of culturally accepted practices has been disjointed. This is due, in part, to a sense of powerlessness from a history of dispossession7 and a history of externally driven and constantly changing government policy.
Increasing recognition is being given to the importance of re-establishing traditional land management practices. At the same time there is increasing loss of Aboriginal social memory and physical capacity to manage country due to poor health and premature death, and the changing priorities of Aboriginal youth8. In many areas we see a negative feedback loop between country and health leading to a downward spiral of poor relative human health and poor ecological health of country.
In this article we explore some of the interrelationships of health outcomes for Aboriginal people in central Australia and the supply of central Australia-based environmental services. In particular we provide economic argument for how, under certain conditions, the joint supply of environmental and health services by a single provider results in scoping economies (see table 1 for a glossary of economic terms). Such economies are characterised by the supply of two or more services through a single provider costing less than would be the case were each service provided by a separate provider. This interconnection between environmental and health services, and the economic efficiency issues in how they may be best supplied, is relevant at the higher levels of government policy-making in decisions about budget allocations across sectors.
Table 1: Glossary of economic terms
Aboriginal participation in land management is less than what is socially desirable because of market failure due to poor market signals (prices). Because Aboriginal people do not enjoy the full benefit of the public goods generated through their participation in land management, these public goods (such as biodiversity) are under-supplied. Governments, among others, can correct for this by providing appropriate incentives.
The issue for the government decision-maker is the selection of the appropriate policy response to facilitate the optimal joint supply of health and environmental services. We propose the cost-effectiveness plane as a simple framework to guide selection. We then discuss the importance of ensuring the incentives provided are consistent with the cultural norms of Aboriginal people.
Issues and interrelationships in health outcomes
Predisposing factors to poor health
The causes of excess morbidity and mortality in the Aboriginal population of central Australia are complex. They include upstream, social determinants, as well as downstream behavioural factors4. The downstream risk relates to behavioural factors affecting the prevalence of chronic disease such as smoking, alcohol abuse, poor diet, lack of physical activity and injury, including interpersonal violence.
Pearson9 has argued a 'radical centrist' view that Aboriginal people not only have rights to health, but that they must also take responsibility for current circumstances in order to take control and modify the behavioural factors affecting their health. Because of the predisposing psychological and social determinants of health10-12 Aboriginal people do not always have adequate opportunity or capacity to address such behavioural factors. It is therefore important to address the predisposing determinants of health in cooperation with and in support of Aboriginal people taking control of the behavioural factors affecting their health.
Social determinants of health
There is a large international volume of work on the social and psychological determinants of health - for example the collection of papers edited by Marmot and Wilkinson12 and the steps taken by the World Health Organization in setting up the Commission on Social Determinants of Health11. The social determinants particularly relevant to this article are those set out by Krieger13.
A small but significant body of literature provides evidence of the observed health benefits of Aboriginal people living on country and undertaking land management on their country, including harvesting and eating bush foods14-18. Cass et al.10 described the link between disadvantage and end-stage renal disease for Aboriginal people. Carson et al.19 reviewed the factors linking Aboriginal health outcomes with their social determinants. However the joint relationship between Aboriginal land management and improved health is poorly accounted for.
The social benefits of addressing Aboriginal health
There is a national commitment from the Australian state to its citizens to ensure delivery of a shared base-level of social services, including education, communications, housing and health. In addition there are strong horizontal and vertical equity and human rights arguments for addressing Aboriginal health, as acknowledged in the National Indigenous Health Equality Targets20.
A number of economic studies provide an indication of the probable value of improved health outcomes for disadvantaged populations. Internationally, the Commission on Macroeconomics and Health estimated that raising the life expectancy of people in low income developing countries from 59 to 68 years of age would result in an annual increase in economic growth of 0.5%21. The Canadian Royal Commission on Aboriginal Peoples estimated an annual loss due to the marginalisation of Native Americans of 1% of gross national production22. This was based on social costs associated with the economic marginalisation of aboriginal people (foregone income) and costs incurred by governments in attempting to address social problems through remedial programs.
While there is no direct economic study of the costs of poor Aboriginal health in central Australia, Barnes et al.23, using the same approach as used in the Canadian study, estimated the annual cost to the Northern Territory (NT) of the social disadvantage suffered by Aboriginal people in 2001 as $1.4 billion. Further, the NT Government and its agencies have identified Aboriginal disadvantage as a key parameter influencing labour productivity and gross state productivity24.
Being 'on country'
For Aboriginal people, involvement in managing country can result in confirmation of identity and cultural authority, social activities, provision of purpose, teaching and sharing knowledge, exercise and food. Contemporary Aboriginal peoples' attachment to country is expressed in various ways including: living on traditional country; visiting their country; and carrying out land management practices, sometimes in collaboration with government or non-government bodies.
Properly initiated and supported, linkages by Aboriginal people with their traditional country have the potential to support the maintenance and reintroduction of land management practices that draw from Aboriginal tradition, and reverse the negative feedback between health and the environment. It is important that Aboriginal people have ownership of how activities that express their relationship with their country and environmental management are set up, managed and run. This is because a sense of control over one's life is a psychosocial determinant of health, and is also critical to motivation and institutional stability, as recognised in the broader economic development literature25.
The practices that Aboriginal people undertake in managing country may include patch burning, control of feral animals, maintenance of language and intergenerational transmission of the ecological knowledge embedded in language and art. The public receives a number of environmental benefits from such practices. For example patch burning acts to mitigate intense, more destructive fires which pose greater risks to fire sensitive habitats and will generate relatively higher rates of greenhouse gas release. By promoting habitat diversity, patch burning contributes to the maintenance of biodiversity, while promoting the regeneration of fire-adapted species.
The private benefits to Aboriginal people from engaging in land management practices on their country may include food and exercise, income from the supply of arts and crafts, and from contracted land management. Enhanced emotional and psychological health as a result of improved cultural knowledge and status within the community can lead to greater capacity to assert control.
Consideration of a holistic approach to Aboriginal health
The importance of a holistic approach is often emphasised in discussion of the achievement of improved Aboriginal health and wellbeing. The medical use of the term refers to the treatment of the whole person. Clapham et al.26 observed that '... a large number of health determinants lie outside the formal health sector', and that '[s]olutions to Indigenous health and development problems need to come from many sectors, not just the health sector' (p.272). Lutschini27 has commented on the lack of cohesion in the '... meanings attached to Aboriginal holistic health [sic]'. Here we rely on a coherent and testable application of 'holistic' as it may be applied to achieving improvements in Aboriginal health.
The economic meaning of a holistic approach
According to common explanations, an advantage of a holistic approach is due to the existence of synergies. Synergies are assumed to exist when the whole (outcome) is greater than the sum of the parts (inputs). In such situations economies of scale are achievable. However, the economies that may be achieved using a holistic approach are not limited to synergies. Indeed, there are circumstances in which the economies of a holistic approach to Aboriginal health are the result of complementary inputs rather than synergies.
Complementary inputs
Complementarities normally occur as a result of a technical link between various inputs that require those inputs to be used in combination. A range of relationships are possible where complementary inputs exist. At one extreme, production will not be possible unless all inputs are present. In other situations, production will occur but productivity will be less than it would be if all complementary inputs were provided at an optimal level. For example, if you have doctors but no clinics or medical equipment, some health outcomes will be achieved, but these will be much less than if the requisite infrastructure were also available.
An economic test of complementary inputs is when a price increase for one of the inputs, such that demand for that input falls, results in a corresponding decrease in the quantity demanded for the complementary inputs. This differs according to the existence of substitutable inputs where a price increase for one input results in an increase in the quantity demanded of the alternate inputs.
The poor outcomes and high cost of health delivery to Aboriginal people in remote central Australia, relative to the situation for the rest of Australia as a whole and to the rest of the remote central Australian community, is consistent with a failure to provide complementary inputs. Notwithstanding any improvements in health service infrastructure and staffing, Aboriginal health and wellbeing will be sub-optimal unless the social and psychological determinants of health are also addressed. This is because the psychosocial determinants of health are complementary inputs to Aboriginal health and wellbeing.
Scoping economies
A further economic characteristic of some complementary inputs is when the joint provision of goods and services results in economies of scope. Scoping economies in the supply of health and environmental services can occur when the cost of providing certain health services in conjunction with the supply of environmental services is less than the cost of providing these services through separate approaches to health service delivery and environmental management.
Scoping economies normally occur as a result of shared inputs. In the provision of health and environmental services, the potential for scoping economies occurs as a result of the technical relationship between the means used to provide environmental services and the derived health benefits. That is, the technical relationship occurs because Aboriginal people are providing knowledge and labour inputs to the supply of environmental services through the use of land management practices that drawn on their cultural traditions. In doing so, Aboriginal people receive a range of biophysical health benefits (such as through exercise) and psychosocial health benefits (such as enhanced self esteem through recognition by others of the value of their knowledge and effort). In this way, health services and environmental services are produced jointly.
Private provision of public goods: The private supply of public goods will depend on the application of appropriate policy tools, which will vary according to the economic characteristic of the services provided and the sum of private and public benefits less costs.
Public goods and private goods: Economists differentiate goods and services according to whether they are private or public goods. A public good is one that is non-rivalrous in consumption or use, such that the enjoyment of a good by one individual does not reduce the amount available to another individual. As a result, the marginal social opportunity cost of consumption is zero. Television signals, information, and defence are examples of public goods. In contrast, private goods are those goods which, when consumed or used, are no longer available to others, and are said to be rivalrous in consumption. In this case, the social opportunity cost of consumption is greater than zero. Food and fuel are examples of private goods.
The provision of health services often involves the joint supply of public and private goods. For example, a treatment that cures someone with an infectious disease has private benefit for that individual and public benefits through the removal of a potential source of infection to the population. In addition, the public may decide to maintain the health of the public at some minimal level.
Environmental services can also involve the joint supply of public good benefits (such as biodiversity) and private good benefits (such as food and firewood). In addition many land management practices jointly provide environmental and health services, which may occur as both private and public goods. An example of this is Aboriginal cleaning and fencing of waterholes in central Australia to exclude feral animals, to protect and conserve water. In addition to cultural benefits, this will result in private benefits through improved quantity and quality of water and an increase in the numbers of native food species. This activity can also result in private health benefits from exercise, improved food and reaffirming of cultural associations. At the same time, public good benefits for the broader community will occur as a result of a more effective public expenditure on meeting socially desirable standards in Aboriginal health and the maintenance of biodiversity.
Are health benefits an externality to the provision of environmental services?
An externality is a benefit or cost due to an activity that is not accounted for when assessing the benefits and costs of the activity. Externalities may be positive, such as when health benefits generated through participation in the supply of environmental services by Aboriginal people are not taken into account by government policy makers. Externalities may also be negative, such as when overgrazing, which results in an increased incidence of dust storms with consequent health impacts28, goes unpriced.
Failure to include health benefits, when accounting for the benefits of Aboriginal land management, will result in land management being under supplied. As a result, the joint supply of health and environmental services will be sub-optimal. Alternatively, goods and services that result in negative externalities will be oversupplied, as per the overgrazing example above.
An example of a positive externality is patch burning, such as is used by Aboriginal women in some central Australian communities to assist them in food collection29. While this activity is carried out to obtain private benefits, it can also generate public environmental benefits such as through the reduction in the risk of intense wild-fires.
A number of government programs have been initiated to facilitate Aboriginal land management practices to increase the supply of public good environmental services30. Public good health benefits are usually not included in the accounting for such government funding. Unless such benefits are fully accounted for, the provision of Aboriginal land management practices will be undersupplied.
This is particularly important within the current policy debate concerning the movement of Aboriginal people from the smaller remote settlements into larger population centres31. While this movement may result in efficiencies in service delivery, it is also likely to result in disengagement from traditional country, intercommunity conflict and resulting poorer health and environmental outcomes. Inter alia, an understanding of the economic relationships between engagement in land management practices and health outcomes has been missing from this debate. For policy-makers interested in generating evidence-based policy, it is important that the information shortfalls concerning this relationship are addressed.
Facilitating the optimal supply of private and public goods
A necessary, though not sufficient, condition for the optimal supply of goods and services is that they continue to be supplied as long as the social benefit of an additional (marginal) unit is at least equal to its cost. Because the cost of providing a public good to an additional person is zero, there is an economic argument to not charge for the supply of public goods. A possible government role is to either supply public goods directly or to provide appropriate incentives for their private provision.
Policy makers need to select a policy response to ensure that Aboriginal people, as private providers, supply land management practices at an optimal level. The available responses are incentives, disincentives, or doing nothing. One method for selecting the appropriate policy response is through the use of the cost-effectiveness plane, shown in Figure 1. This policy decision tool has been used in a number of different policy arenas, including health32, water resource management33 and land management34.
In using the cost-effectiveness plane we assume that the benefits to the broad Australian public from Aboriginal land management practices are public goods, and that the benefits to the Aboriginal people undertaking land management are private goods.
Figure 1: Cost effectiveness plane for resolving the application of private incentives.
Figure 1 represents the full range of all possibilities attributable to Aboriginal land management practices. The vertical axis shows public benefits, which can be positive or negative. The horizontal axis shows private benefits, which can be positive or negative. Private benefits are the benefits less the costs incurred by Aboriginal people from their land management practices. Public benefits are the benefits that accrue to the broader public from Aboriginal land management practices less any costs that the broader public incur as a result of these practices.
Figure 1 is divided diagonally into two halves. Below the diagonal line the sum of private benefits plus public benefits result in a negative total social benefit. In the area above the diagonal line the sum of private benefits plus public benefits results in positive total social benefit. For example, points L and M represent two land management possibilities.
At L, located below the diagonal line (Fig1) there is a private loss of 0Lprivate and a public benefit of 0Lpublic. The total social benefit of L, given by equation (E1), is shown to be negative:
Social benefit L = (0Lpublic) - (0Lprivate) < 0[E1]
For point M (located above the diagonal line) there is a private loss of 0Mprivate and a public benefit of 0Mpublic. The total social benefit of M given by equation (E2) is shown to be positive:
Social benefit M = (0Mpublic) - (0Mprivate) > 0[E2]
Selection of policy mechanisms
In segment A quadrant 1 (Fig1), the private benefit to Aboriginal landowners from undertaking land management practices is negative (such as at point L) - that is, there is a private loss. Although there is a public benefit, the private loss exceeds the public benefit, so that the net social benefit is negative (E1). This is represented by this segment being below the diagonal line. Hence this land management practice should not be carried out.
In segment 1B a mix of private loss and public benefit continue to exist (such as point M). However in this segment, the public benefit exceeds the private loss, such that the net social benefit of undertaking the land management activities is positive (E2). Hence this land management practice should be carried out.
Nevertheless because there is a private loss, land management practices in this segment will not be undertaken by landowners without some form of incentive. The value of the incentive to the landowners will need to be at least as great as the private loss incurred from undertaking the necessary land management activities. The rate at which the incentive generates increased private land management will depend on the extent to which the value of the incentive exceeds the private loss. The marginal cost of applying the incentive will need to be no greater than the marginal value of the increase in public benefit.
In quadrant 2 landowners realise a private benefit from undertaking land management practices that also generate public benefit. As a result the net social benefit is positive, as indicated by the location of quadrant 2 above the diagonal line. Landowners will engage in these land management practices because of the positive private benefit, and no policy intervention is warranted.
In quadrant 3, there are positive private benefits from land management practices, but negative public benefits. For segment 3A, the private benefit from engaging in land management practices is greater than the public loss, as indicated by the location of this segment above the diagonal line. As a result the net total social benefit from land management practices located in this segment is positive. Thus, in spite of the public loss, it is appropriate for these land management practices to occur and no policy intervention is warranted.
In segment 3B the public loss is greater than the private benefit, such that the net social benefit is negative, as indicated by the location of this segment below the diagonal line. Landowners will implement the land management practices that are located in this segment because of the private benefit they gain, despite the social loss from the negative public benefit exceeds the net private benefit. The appropriate policy response, to avoid socially harmful land management practices, is to implement some form of negative incentive or sanction, such as a fine. To provide an effective deterrent, the cost to landowners from such sanctions needs to be at least as great as their net private benefit from carrying out the practice multiplied by the probability of being caught and sanctioned.
In quadrant 4, both the private and public benefits from land management practices are negative - there are both private and public losses. Because private benefit is negative, landowners will not undertake land management practices located in this segment. Hence no policy intervention is required.
Behavioural incentives
The design of incentives - what they are applied to, their extent, timing and how they are applied - is critical if they are to be effective in the joint supply of environmental and health services. Incentives will need to be compatible with Aboriginal culture and preferences if appropriate responses from Aboriginal people are to occur.
The effectiveness of policy mechanisms aimed at optimising economic outcomes from the joint supply of environmental and health services depends on assumptions regarding human preferences and behaviour. Aboriginal people are likely to have different preference functions from the non-Aboriginal community. This highlights the importance of Aboriginal people having control over how environmental services and health services are provided. If we expect Aboriginal people to take responsibility for behavioural factors affecting their health9, it is important that policy actions that aim to facilitate this are compatible with Aboriginal cultural practices.
Conclusion
Two important concerns in central Australia of national relevance are the continuing Aboriginal 'mortality gap' relative to all Australia, and the loss of environmental services including biodiversity. Not only are these two concerns interrelated, but dealing with them is inextricably connected through the psychosocial determinants of health.
Aboriginal control of land management can result in economies through the joint supply of environmental and health services. This holistic relationship is due to the existence of complementary inputs. Failure to deliver the complementary inputs that are offered by Aboriginal land management will result in sub-optimal effectiveness in the delivery of health services.
The benefits from joint supply of environmental and health services may take the form of private goods that are of benefit to the Aboriginal landowners, and public goods that are of benefit to the broader community. Because Aboriginal people derive little benefit from the public goods that they provide through land management, they have little incentive to provide a socially optimal level of land management. One way of correcting for this is for government or some other body to provide appropriate incentives.
The issue for government decision-makers is the selection of appropriate policy tools. The cost-effectiveness plane provides a simple framework to guide the design of policy responses. This approach is a step to addressing an outstanding research need. That is an economic assessment of the total national social benefit from Aboriginal engagement in land management, including a closer examination of the relative strengths and weaknesses concerning Aboriginal people in central Australia living in dispersed small settlements, relative to increasing centralisation.
Acknowledgements
The authors acknowledge the assistance provided by Quentin Grafton of the Crawford School of Economics and Government, Australian National University College of Asia and the Pacific; Pim Kuipers of the Centre for Remote Health; our co-workers and the many others who provided the conversation in which to test our thoughts. The work reported in this publication was jointly supported by funding from the Australian Government Cooperative Research Centre Program through the Desert Knowledge CRC and the Centre for Remote Health, funded by the Department of Health and Ageing University Department of Rural Health program. The views expressed herein do not necessarily represent the views of Desert Knowledge CRC, the Centre for Remote Health or its participants.
References
1. Australian Institute of Health and Welfare. Australia's Health 2006, The Tenth Biennial Report of the Australian Institute of Health and Welfare. AIHW cat no AUS 73. Canberra, ACT: AIHW, 2006.
2. Mitchell J, Pearce RSM, Taylor J, Warchivker I. Indigenous Populations and Resource Flows in Central Australia: A Social and Economics Baseline Profile. Alice Springs, NT: Report prepared by the Centre for Remote Health, Aboriginal and Torres Strait Islander Commission and Australian National University, 2005.
3. Australian Institute of Health and Welfare. Diabetes hospitalisations in Australia, 2003-04. Bulletin Canberra, ACT: AIHW, 2006; 47.
4. Thomas DP, Condon JR, Anderson IP, Li SQ, Halpin S, Cunningham J et al. Long-term trend in Indigenous deaths from chronic diseases in the Northern Territory: a foot on the brake, a foot on the accelerator. Medical Journal of Australia 2006; 185(3): 145-149.
5. Gale SJ, Haworth RJ. Catchment-wide soil loss from pre-agricultural times to the present: transport- and supply-limitation of erosion. Geomorphology 2005; 45: 417-430.
6. Lunt ID, Eldridge DJ, Morgan JW, Witt BG. A framework to predict the effects of livestock grazing and grazing exclusion on conservation values in natural ecosystems in Australia. Turner review no. 13. Australian Journal of Botany 2007; 55(4): 401-415.
7. Whiteside M, Tsey K, McCalman J, Cadet-James Y, Wilson A. Empowerment as a framework for Indigenous workforce development and organisational change. Australian Social Worker 2006; 59(4): 422-434.
8. Davies J. For healthy country and healthy people: Indigenous land management in central Australia. In: Proceedings, Australian Rangeland Society 13th Biennial Conference; July 2004; Alice Springs, NT; 2004.
9. Pearson N. White guilt, victimhood and the quest for a radical centre. Griffith Review 2007; May: 12-57.
10. Cass A, Cunningham J, Snelling P, Wang Z, Hoy W. Exploring the pathways leading from disadvantage to end-stage renal disease for Indigenous Australians. Social Science & Medicine 2004; 58: 767-785.
11. Irwin A, Scali E. Action on the social determinants of health: learning from previous experiences. Geneva: Commission on Social determinants of Health, Secretariat of the Commission on Social Determinants of Health, World Health Organization, 2005.
12. Marmot M, Wilkinson RG (Eds). Social determinants of heath. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999.
13. Krieger N. A glossary for social epidemiology. Journal of Epidemiology and Community Health 2001; 55: 693-700.
14. Rowley KG, O'Dea K, Anderson I, McDermott R, Saraswati K, Tilmouth R et al. Lower than expected morbidity and mortality for an Australian Aboriginal population: 10-year follow-up in a decentralised community. Medical Journal of Australia 2008; 188(5): 283-287.
15. Garnett S, Sithole B. Sustainable northern landscapes and the nexus with Indigenous health: healthy country health people. Canberra, ACT: Department of Land and Water Australia, 2007.
16. Burgess CP, Johnston FH, Bowman DMJS, Whitehead PJ. Healthy country, healthy people? Exploring the health benefits of Indigenous natural resource management. Australian New Zealand Journal of Public Health 2005; 29: 117-122.
17. McDermott R, O'Dea K, Rowley K, Knight S, Burgess P. Beneficial impact of the Homeland Movement on health outcomes in central Australian Aborigines. Australian and New Zealand Journal of Public Health 1998; 22(6): 653-658.
18. O'Dea K. Marked improvement in carbohydrate and lipid metabolism in diabetic Australian Aborigines after temporary reversion to traditional lifestyle. Diabetes 1984; 33: 596-603.
19. Carson B, Dunbar T, Chenhall RD, Bailie R (Eds). Introduction. In: B Carson, T Dunbar, RD Chenhall, R Bailie (Eds). Social determinants of Indigenous health. Sydney: Allen & Unwin, 2007; xix-xxix.
20. Aboriginal and Social Justice Commission. Close the Gap: National Indigenous Health Equality Targets. Australian Aboriginal and Torres Strait Islander Social Justice Commissioner and the Steering Committee for Indigenous Health. Outcomes from the National Indigenous Health Equality Summit. Canberra, ACT: Commonwealth Government, 2008.
21. Sachs JD. Macro economics and health: investing in health for economic development. Report of the Commission on Macroeconomics and Health. Geneva: WHO, 2001
22. Canadian Royal Commission on Aboriginal Peoples. Renewal: a twenty year commitment. In Report of the Royal Commission on Aboriginal Peoples, volume 5, chapter 2, Canadian Government, Ottawa. (Online) 1996. Available: http://www.ainc-inac.gc.ca/ch/rcap/sg/sk3_e.html (Accessed 22 September 2008).
23. Barnes A, Rummery S, Michel T, Sargeant M. The special case of the Northern Territory. Canberra, ACT: Commonwealth-State Forum on Economic Framework Issues, 2006.
24. Northern Territory Government. 2007/08 Budget: Fiscal and Economic Outlook. Darwin, NT: Northern Territory Government Printing Office, 2007.
25. Ostrom E. Crafting institutions for self-governing irrigation systems. San Francisco: International centre for Self Governance, ICS Press, 1992.
26. Clapham K, O'Dea K, Chenhall RD. Interventions and sustainable programs. B Carson, T Dunbar, RD Chenhall, R Bailie (Eds). Social determinants of Indigenous health. Sydney: Allen & Unwin, 2007; 271-291.
27. Lutschini, M. Engaging with holism in Australian Aboriginal health - a review. Australia and New Zealand Health Policy 2005; 2: 15.
28. Campbell D, Stafford Smith M, Davies J, Kuipers P, Wakerman J, McGregor MJ. Responding to health impacts of climate change in the Australian desert. Rural and Remote Health 8: 1008. (Online) 2008. Available: http://www.rrh.org.au (Accessed 22 September 2008).
29. Bird DW, Bird RB, Parker CH. Aboriginal burning regimes and hunting strategies in Australia's Western Desert. Human Ecology 2005; 33(4): 443-463.
30. Roughley A,Williams S. The engagement of Indigenous Australians in natural resource management: key findings and outcomes from land & water Australia funded research and the broader literature. Canberra, ACT: Land and Water Australia, 2007.
31. Hughes H, Warin J. A new deal for Aborigines and Torres Strait Islanders in remote communities. Issue analysis no 54. Sydney, NSW: Centre for Independent Studies, 2005. Available: http://www.cis.org.au/issue_analysis/IA54/IA54.PDF (Accessed 3 September 2008).
32. Willan AR, Briggs AH. Statistical analysis of cost-effectiveness data. Chichester: John Wiley and Sons, 2006.
33. Grafton Q. An economic evaluation of the national plan for water security. In: Q Grafton, J Bennett, K Hussey (Eds). Dry water. Policy Briefs. Canberra, ACT: Crawford School of Economics and Government, ANU College of Asia and the Pacific, 2007.
34. Pannell D. Public benefits, private benefits, and policy mechanisms for land-use change for environmental benefits. Land Economics 2008; 84(2): 225-240.